BILL ANALYSIS AB 226 PageA Date of Hearing: April 13, 2009 ASSEMBLY COMMITTEE ON NATURAL RESOURCES Nancy Skinner, Chair AB 226 (Ruskin) - As Introduced: February 4, 2009 SUBJECT : Coastal Commission: enforcement. SUMMARY : Authorizes the California Coastal Commission (Commission) to administratively impose civil penalties in an enforcement case against anyone in violation of the Coastal Act of 1976. EXISTING LAW : 1)Pursuant to the California Coastal Act of 1976, requires any person wishing to perform any development in the coastal zone to first obtain a coastal development permit (CDP). 2)Authorizes the Commission, after a public hearing, to issue a cease and desist order if it determines that someone is undertaking or threatening to undertake any activity that requires a CDP or that may be inconsistent with a previously issued permit. 3)Authorizes the Commission, a local government, or port, after a public hearing, to issue a restoration order if it finds that development has occurred without a CDP and the development is causing continuing resource damage. 4)Authorizes a superior court to impose civil penalties on any person in violation of the Coastal Act between $500 and $30,000 per violation; additional penalties between $1,000 and $15,000 per day for each day in which a violation persists may be imposed when anyone knowingly and intentionally violates the Coastal Act. THIS BILL : 1)Authorizes the Commission, at a duly noticed public hearing, to administratively impose civil penalties in an enforcement case against anyone in violation of the Coastal Act of 1976 in an amount not less than $5000 and not to exceed $50,000 for each violation. AB 226 PageB 2)In determining the amount of civil liability, requires the Commission to consider: a. the nature, circumstance, extent, and gravity of the violation; b. whether the violation is susceptible to restoration or other remedial measures; c. the sensitivity of the resource affected by the violation; d. the cost to the state of bringing the action. e. with respect to the violator, any voluntary restoration or remedial measures undertaken, any prior history of violations, the degree of culpability, economic profits, if any, resulting from, or expected to result as a consequence of, the violation, and such other matters as justice may require. 3)Exempts a violator from civil monetary liability imposed by the Commission and by a superior court for the same act or failure to act, unless the violator fails to pay the administrative penalty, fails to comply with an order issued by the Commission, or if a violator decides to challenge the Commission's action in court. 4)Authorizes the Commission to file a lien on the subject property if a violator fails to pay the penalties. 5)Deposits all penalties into the Coastal Act Services Fund, the monies of which, upon appropriation by the Legislature, can be used to enforce the Coastal Act and provide services to local government, permit applicants, and the public. FISCAL EFFECT : Unknown COMMENTS : According to the author's office, "[p]enalties are a critical component of environmental statutes and are the main means used to persuade would-be violators to comply with the law. A credible threat of penalties to prevent violations in the first place can greatly increase the ability of an environmental agency to obtain voluntary compliance, and significantly increase protection of the environment. The deterrent component of any regulatory scheme is important, particularly for environmental laws where restoration of violations often is difficult or impossible, and cannot make the resource whole." AB 226 PageC 1)Commission lacks the sharpest and most cost-effective tool to achieve deterrence The ability for an agency to impose administrative civil penalties is but one tool in an enforcement toolkit and must be distinguished from civil penalties imposed by a court and criminal penalties. According to Rechtschaffen and Markell, "The essential task for enforcement agencies is to make penalties high enough and the probability of detection great enough that it becomes economically irrational for regulated entities to violate the law."<1> U.S EPA's policy on civil penalties states that the first goal of penalty assessment is deterrence, which is achieved when the penalty places the violator in a worse position than those who complied in a timely fashion. At a minimum, the policy states that the penalty must remove any significant economic benefits from failure to comply with the law. If they set high enough, administrative penalties can be the most cost-effective enforcement tool, obviating the need to pursue expensive litigation, at taxpayer's expense, in court. Only a court can impose civil penalties on violators of the Coastal Act. This is a time-consuming and resource-intensive process. Since the Attorney General (AG) must represent the Commission in court, the Commission can only pursue a small percentage of all violators given its limited resources. Since 2003, the Commission has only pursued four cases in court (though it also pursues cross-complaints when sued). Considering these constraints, court-imposed penalties have a limited deterrent effect on would-be violators who may decide that violating the Coastal Act is worth the risk especially since they do not have to pay any fines or even compensate the Commission for the costs of investigations. --------------------------- <1> C. Rechtschaffen, and D. Markell, 2003. Reinventing environmental enforcement and the state/federal relationship . Environmental Law Institute. Washington, D.C. AB 226 PageE 2)Commission is late to the party As arguably the state's most significant land use regulator, the Commission lacks one of the most effective enforcement tools. Agencies such as the San Francisco Bay Conservation and Development Commission (BCDC), the State Water Resources Control Board (and regional boards), State Lands Commission, Department of Fish and Game, California Energy Commission, Air Resources Board, Department of Forestry, Department of Toxic Substances Control, Integrated Waste Management Board, Department of Health Services, Department of Food and Agriculture, Structural Pest Control Board, regional air districts, and local agencies all have administrative civil penalty authority. BCDC's authority to regulate development along San Francisco Bay serves as the best analog to the work of the Commission. Using its civil penalty authority, BCDC has been successful at discouraging and resolving the vast majority of violations without resorting to expensive and time consuming litigation. Given this anomaly, and the foregoing, it is entirely reasonable and in the public's interest for the Commission to have the same authority. The Legislative Analyst Office (LAO) recommended as much in its 2008-09 analysis of the budget and the Budget Subcommittee #3 adopted this recommendation. However, this recommendation was later dropped from the budget. 3)The Commission's cease and desist authority encourages non-cooperation In order to stop on-going violations, the Commission is authorized to issue cease and desist orders. Using this authority, the Commission has been able to resolve some violations amicably through the use of consent orders, under which a violator usually agrees to pay a penalty. However, the violator has to voluntarily agree to pay since the Commission has no authority to impose such a penalty. According to Commission staff, a violator usually ends up paying a much smaller penalty than that which could be imposed by a court. However, the irony is that those violators who contest an order usually pay nothing since they are aware that the Commission has to go to court to pursue penalties. Thus, it pays to be recalcitrant and roll the dice given that the odds of litigation are slim. This creates a perverse incentive for non-cooperation. The Commission's enforcement statistics may, in part, bolster this claim: there is a current backlog of 1,300 AB 226 PageF cases; from 1985-2008, the balance of its enforcement account has averaged only about $134,000. 4)Opposition alleges that "bounty-hunting" would ensue under AB 226 Among other things, a coalition of opponents argues that this bill "creates a 'bounty hunter' dynamic whereby the [Commission] is incentivized to seek large penalties and fees to support its budget." In response, Commission staff states that the bill only authorizes penalties in the amount no less than $5,000 and no more than $50,000 per violation. Moreover, even if the Commission desired to bolster its budget, it currently only has one statewide enforcement staff to pursue a backlog of over 1,300 cases. Since the 2002-03 budget, the Commission has endured significant cuts to its funding. Its skeleton staff can no longer process permits in a timely manner, it can no longer comment on projects at the local level (which can lead to delays when projects move to the Commission), and amendments to Local Coastal Plans can languish for two years or more. Furthermore, any administrative penalty would be subject to judicial review; the Commission argues that any penalty sought as a "bounty" would not withstand this review. It is also worth noting that BCDC received $113,000 in civil penalties last year, hardly a "bounty" by any definition. 5)Enforcement revenues can be used by Commission Under existing law, all enforcement revenues are transferred to the Coastal Conservancy (Conservancy) to fund its coastal access program. In response to a LAO recommendation, this bill would delete this transfer and instead deposit all enforcement revenues in the Coastal Act Services Fund (Fund), established to carry out the Commission's enforcement program and to provide services to local government, permit applicants, and others. This would reduce the Conservancy's coastal access funding by about $134,000. However, the Conservancy would still be entitled to about $500,000 annually from the Fund, as required by existing law. 6)Dual-referral This bill has been dual-referred to the Assembly Judiciary Committee. The author has agreed to clarify the "double jeopardy" provisions in subdivision (d) in this committee. The AB 226 PageG author should also consider amending the bill to include evidentiary rules and process considerations similar to those that are contained in the Commissions regulations (Title 14, Division 5.5, Section 13186) or in BCDC's statute. REGISTERED SUPPORT / OPPOSITION : Support California Coastal Commission California Coast Keeper Alliance Environment California Heal the Bay Natural Resources Defense Council Planning and Conservation League Sierra Club California Opposition American Council of Engineering Companies of California California Association of REALTORS California Business Properties Association California Building Industry Association California Chamber of Commerce California Manufacturers and Technology Association Industrial Environmental Association Analysis Prepared by : Dan Chia / NAT. RES. / (916) 319-2092